Households
Building the budget constraint
Individuals live for two periods. As before, we assume perfect foresight for individuals. Assumption OLG.1 Individuals have perfect foresight.
When young, they are endowed with one unit of labour that they supply inestastically. Assumption OLG.2 Individuals supply one unit of labour inelastically when young. They receive the ongoing wage rate $w_{t}$ and allocate this income between:
- current consumption $c_{t}$,
- savings $s_{t}$ that are invested in the firms.
Therefore, the budget constraint of a young individual in period $t$ is:
$$ w_{t} = c_{t} + s_{t}.$$
Once an individual reaches old age the next period, he consumes his savings (plus the interest rate received), reproduces —exogenous fertility at rate $n$— and dies. Old people do not care about anything happening after death. Therefore, an agent has one unique choice:
- consumption when adult, $d_{t+1}.$
The budget constraint for this period is:1
$$s_{t}(1 - \delta + r_{t+1}) = d_{t+1}.$$
with $\delta \in (0,1)$ being the capital depreciation rate.
Hence, an individual faces two budget constraints. However, we can collapse both into a unique intertemporal budget constraint.
The intertemporal budget constraint
In the economy, we have consumption as the numeraire. It is more convenient for us to combine the two budget constraints corresponding to young and old ages into one single constraint. Starting from
$$\left. \begin{eqnarray} w_{t} = c_{t} + s_{t} \\\ d_{t+1} = s_{t}(1 - \delta + r_{t+1}) = s_{t} R_{t+1} \end{eqnarray} \right\}.$$
where $R_{t} \equiv 1 - \delta + r_{t+1}$ represents the return on savings, isolate $s_{t}$ in the second equation and plug it in the first one:
$$ w_{t} = c_{t} + \frac{d_{t+1}}{R_{t+1}}. \tag{1, Int. Budget Const.} \label{eq:budget}$$
The intertemporal budget constraint indicates that the total present value of income ($w_{t}$, the only source of income) equals the total present value of expenditures. The present value of consumption when old $d_{t+1}$ is discounted using the interest rate $R_{t+1}.$
It is clear that savings, as usual, will be a function of wages $w$ and interests $R.$ So will consumption at all periods of time.
Utility function
We suppose that the life-cycle utility function is additively separable:
$$U(c,d) = u( c ) + \beta u(d),, \beta \in(0,1) \tag{2, Utility} \label{eq:utility}$$
where $\beta \in (0,1)$ is the psychological discount factor. We assume that $u( c )$ has the properties
Assumption OLG.3
- OLG.3.1 $u^{\prime}( c ) > 0,$
- OLG.3.2 $u^{\prime \prime} ( c ) < 0,$
- OLG.3.3 $ \lim_{c \rightarrow 0} u^{\prime}( c) = +\infty.$
The last assumption $\lim_{c \rightarrow 0} u^{\prime}( c ) = +\infty$ implies that an individual will always have a positive consumption —as long as he has enough income to finance it.
Another important implication of the choice of the utility formulation is that $c$ and $d$ are normal goods: the demand is not decreasing in wealth. It follows from additive separability and concavity. In the Appendix we discuss it in more detail for a non-separable utility function.
The behaviour of individuals
At time $t$, young individuals receive their wages, consume and save while maximising the utility function.
$$\begin{eqnarray} & \max u(c_{t}) + \beta u(d_{t+1}) \\\ & \mathrm{s.t.} \quad w_{t} = c_{t} + s_{t} \\\ & \phantom{s.t.} \quad d_{t+1} = R_{t+1}s_{t} \\\ & \phantom{s.t.} \quad c_{t} \geq 0, d_{t+1} \geq 0. \end{eqnarray}$$
We have two possibilities to solve this problem:
Substitution
First, we can substitute $c_{t}$ and $d_{t+1}$ in the utility function, leading to:
$$u(w_{t} - s_{t}) + \beta u(R_{t+1}s_{t}).$$
This function is strictly concave with respect to $s_{t}$ because of our assumptions. The solution is the savings function:
$$s_{t} = s(w_{t}, R_{t+1}).$$
The solution is interior as a consequence of the assumptions, and it is characterised by the first-order condition:
$$u^{\prime}(w_{t} - s_{t}) = \beta R_{t+1} u^{\prime}(R_{t+1}s_{t}).$$
Lagrangian
Instead, we can use the intertemporal budget constraint and build the Lagrangian:
$$\mathcal{L} = u(c_{t}) + \beta u(d_{t+1}) + \lambda_{t}(w_{t} - c_{t} - \frac{d_{t+1}}{R_{t+1}}).$$
The first order conditions imply that:
$$u^{\prime}(c_{t}) = \lambda_{t}, \quad \beta u^{\prime}(d_{t+1}) = \frac{\lambda_{t}}{R_{t+1}}$$
Combining both, we obtain the Euler equation:
$$u^{\prime}(c_{t}) = \beta R_{t+1} u^\prime (d_{t+1}).$$
-
There plenty of alternative notations for the OLG model. One may write $c^{y}_{t}$ and $c^{o}_{t}$ for young and adult consumption. Similarly, the subindeces $t, t+1, \ldots$ denote the period of consumption, but we could have denoted the period in which the individual was born. ↩︎